Ernest Mandel discusses the
tension in the relationship of university education to capitalist accumulation
in p260ff of Late Capitalism. Late
capitalism, i.e., capitalism in which technological advancement has become the
main impetus for continued accumulation, depends on the production and
reproduction of intellectually skilled labor. For this purpose, universities
were drafted or converted from humanist institutions into knowledge and
knowledge-worker factories. By 1970 when he was writing this book, it was
already clear that universities would become centers for technological
innovation and hence workplaces of capitalist production. That is, humanities
education, moral education, and other traditional notions of the purpose of
higher education, were dissolved. Only very few intellectually skilled workers
need any type of humanist or artistic education—specifically, those who will
produce the ideological arts (science fiction, comic books, TV, movies).
An inevitable clash occurs when a large number of people
begin to demand higher education in order to enter more lucrative fields,
because this drive for upward mobility conflicts with the aims and needs of
capitalists. Not many intellectually skilled workers are needed, and always a
dwindling number in comparison to the quantity of constant capital (dead labor
in the form of extant technology): the more technological sophistication and
automation the intellectually-skilled workers produce for capitalists, the
fewer intellectually-skilled workers are needed for capitalists to accumulate
wealth and profit.
Thus far, the rise of political conflict related to
de-funding higher education makes perfect sense. Capitalists, represented by
legislators, or directly acting politically in the form of tax revolts, refuse
to pay for mass scale higher education, for the simple reason that it is not in
their interests. The vanishing middle class continues to expect and make rather
feeble demands on the state for funding of higher education. The bargain struck
between them has led to the erosion over time of tax supported higher education
and the shift to debt funding.
There’s another story, less economic and more political,
that I think is true and helps explain the situation. Mandel’s analysis sets
higher education somewhat outside the main capitalist economy (oddly, similarly
to the way economists he criticizes heartily later on set the arms economy
outside the main capitalist economy). Viewed another way, what has happened is
that capitalists have pressed a demand for the territory of education as a new
market. In fact, capitalists have demanded not only higher education, but the
entire territory of education, from pre-K on up. This makes perfect sense:
enormous amounts of money are spent on education, meaning that there is a pool
of potential capital circulating through these institutions. While capitalist
accumulation is threatened by diminishing rate of profit in the established
territories of capitalist production (Marx’ famous Departments I and II),
opening a new territory, gaining access to new pots of money to convert into
capital, and restructuring the entire territory on the capitalist factory model
could avert further crisis, until the money runs out. (This, by the way, is
very similar to theories of the permanent arms economy that Mandel agrees most
with—tax funding supplies a source of previously untapped capital, and the
production activity itself provides a way to valorize accumulated capital. That maintaining the arms economy as a profitable venture depends on deliberately destroying both the arms and people has an analogy in education that I will leave to the reader to contemplate for now. Enjoy.)
Education is being rapidly capitalized, through direct
seizure of some schools (the so-called charter schools), but mainly through
imposition of curriculum, through legislation that requires use of particular
pedagogies, textbooks, standardized tests, etc. that are published by major
firms. Standardizing the K-12 curriculum is precisely the replacement of variable capital (labor) with constant
capital (technology), which lowers the value and cost of labor by
simultaneously minimizing numbers of workers needed and allowing for a
reduction of wages. The effort to extend this process into higher education is
already well underway.
Then there are the labor conditions to consider. Here,
higher education has been in the vanguard, because of the resistance of
organized labor in the K-12 sector. Real wages, and the job protections of
tenure, have been largely eliminated from higher education, as the result of a
bargain not at all unlike that struck infamously between auto manufacturers and
UAW leadership beginning in the 1970s or so: a smaller more permanent
workforce, grandfathered in, were guaranteed continuing employment, income, and
pension rights, at the expense of all future employees. The work conditions,
income, and real job protections of workers in the auto industry or higher
education in the 1970s look like unbelievable dreams to the workers of
today—such has been the destruction of labor conditions in these industries. Labor
in higher education has been entirely subjected to “free market” competition,
which is to say, labor on the terms dictated by capitalists. This is why tenure
has to be eliminated, after all, according to every education manager: it
interferes with “flexibility” that the university needs to hire according to “market
demand” (which means, in reality, the absolute authority to create and control
an industrial reserve army, lower wages, and exploit workers).
No comments:
Post a Comment